Abstract
Introduction
Data
Statistical Estimation
Concluding Remarks
Endnotes
References
Abstract
This paper studies the effect of corruption on foreign direct investment.
The sample covers bilateral investment from fourteen source countries
to forty-five host countries during 1990-91. There are three central findings.
(1) A rise in either the tax rate on multinational firms or the corruption
level in a host country reduces inward foreign direct investment (FDI).
An increase in the corruption level from that of Singapore to that of
Mexico is equivalent to raising the tax rate by over twenty percentage
points. (2) There is no support for the hypothesis that corruption has
a smaller effect on FDI into East Asian host countries. (3) American investors
are averse to corruption in host countries, but not necessarily more so
than average OECD investors, in spite of the U.S. Foreign Corrupt Practices
Act of 1977. On the other hand, there is some weak support for the hypothesis
that Japanese investors may be somewhat less sensitive to corruption.
Neither American nor Japanese investors treat corruption in East Asia
any differently from that in other parts of the world.
There are other interesting and sensible findings. For example, consistent
with theories that emphasize the importance of networks in trade and investment,
sharing a common linguistic tie between the source and host countries
and geographic proximity between the two are associated with a sizable
increase in the bilateral FDI flow.
JEL codes: F02 and F23
Send correspondence to: Shang-Jin Wei, Kennedy School of Government,
Harvard University, 79 JFK Street, Cambridge, MA 02138, USA. Fax: (617)
496-5747. Email: [email protected]. Home page: http://www.nber.org/~wei.
Acknowledgement: I would like to thank Kimberly Ann Elliott, John Gallup,
Daniel Kaufman, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, James Hines, Robert Lawrence,
Susan RoseAckerman, Ray Vernon and seminar participants at Harvard University
and University of Southern California for helpful discussion, Greg Dorchak,
Junling Wang, and especially Huamao Bai for efficient research assistance,
and Mihir Desai, Paolo Mauro and Xiaolun Sun for supplying some of the
data. I also wish to acknowledge gratefully the financial support from
The Japan-United States Friendship Commission, a U.S. government agency.
The views presented in the paper are mine, and not necessarily shared
by any other individual or organization.
"We need to deal with the cancer of corruption .... We can give
advice, encouragement, and support to governments that wish to fight corruption
- and it is these governments that, over time, will attract the larger
volume of investment." (Emphasis added).
James D. Wolfensohn1
President, The World Bank
Introduction
This paper studies three sets of questions regarding the effect of corruption
on international direct investment. First, does corruption in host countries
affect negatively their ability to attract foreign direct investment (FDI)?
How big is the effect relative to the host governments' tax on foreign
corporations? Second, is East Asia a special group of host countries?
I will test the hypothesis that corruption has no or reduced effect on
inward FDI in the region, possibly because corruption has been part of
the culture or a way of life for a long time. Third, is the United States
a special source country? I will test the hypothesis that the American
investors are especially sensitive to host country corruption, possibly
due to the deterrent effect of the U.S. Foreign Corrupt Practices Act.
I will explain the three questions in turn.
This first question is partly motivated by the observation on China.
China has rampant corruption according to various newspaper accounts as
well as surveys of business executives2 Yet, for every year
in the last four, China has been the largest developing host of international
investment. Even its FDI flow-to-GDP ratio has been among the highest
among developing countries.
Empirical evidence on a negative correlation between corruption and inward
FDI has so far been elusive. In a study of U.S. firms' foreign investment,
Wheeler and Mody (1992) failed to find a significant correlation between
size of FDI and host country's risk factor, a composite measure that includes
perception of corruption as one of the components. The authors concluded
(p70) that the importance of the risk factor should "be discounted,
although it would not be impossible to assign it some small weight as
a decision factor."
Similarly, more recently, using total inward FDI (as opposed to bilateral
FDI used in this paper), Hines (1995) failed to find a negative correlation
between total inward FDI and corruption level in host countries. Commenting
on his Table A6, Hines remarked (footnote 24 on page 20), "while
the equations fit poorly, it is noteworthy that local corruption has an
insignificant effect on post-1977 growth of FDI..."3
On the other hand, popular press and policy circles seem to believe that
corruption does reduce inward FDI, as suggested by the opening quote from
James Wolfensohn, President of the World Bank. So why is the empirical
evidence so elusive? Wheeler and Mody (1992) mixed the corruption measure
together with 12 other indicators to form one regressor (what the authors
called "RISK"). These other indicators include "attitude
of opposition groups towards FDI," "government support, for
private business activity," and "overall living environment
for expatriates," which may not be overwhelmingly correlated with
government corruption, may not be precisely measured, or may not be as
important for FDI as one imagines. As a result, the noise-to-signal ratio
for the composite measure (RISK) may be too high to show up significantly
in the regressions. In the part of the Hines' paper (1995) that deals
with this question, the total inward FDI from the IMF's IFS database may
also be too noisy.
The first objective of this paper is to reexamine the corruption effect
on a broader panel of bilateral FDI data with a more comprehensive list
of control variables. To reveal the "bottom line", I will report
evidence that corruption in a host country does depress inward FDI in
a way that is statistically significant and quantitatively large.
The second motivation of the paper concerns East Asia as a host region.
By popular account, many East Asian countries have a high level of corruption.
Aside from the China example that was mentioned above, Indonesia is another
apparent paradox. President Suharto is known as "Mr. Ten Percent,"
as foreign corporations doing business there are naturally expected to
pay a relatively well-defined bribe to the President or members of his
family. Yet, Indonesia is a popular destination of FDI, particularly those
from Japan, To see the rapid influx of the FDI into the region, consider
the observation by the United Nations' World Investment Directory 1992,
Vol.1(p14)
"Since 1986, the Asia-Pacific region has become the largest recipient
of FDI among developing countries, accounting for about half of all flows
to the third world. In the late 1980s, FDI flows to Asia and the Pacific
grew rapidly. Average annual investment flows into most Asian and Pacific
countries increased faster between 1960-82 and 1986-88 than between 1975-77
and 1980-82. In the case of the newly industrializing economies and ASEAN
member countries, those flows increased by a factor of 3 (a factor of
7 for the Republic of Korea) between 1980-82 and 1986-88 (with the exception
of Singapore) and by a factor of 13 for China during the same periods.
"
One possible hypothesis is that corruption has been part of the culture
in these economies for a long time. Countervailing institutions may have
been developed to circumvent corruption so that its negative effect on
FDI is minimized. An alternative hypothesis is that East Asia is not special.
The large volume of FDI into East Asia is a response to the region's higher
than average growth rate. Within the East Asia region, foreign investment
still prefers to go to less corrupt countries. In other words, had the
corrupt countries in the region been less so, they would have attracted
even more FDL The second objective of the paper is to discriminate between
the competing hypotheses. As far as I know, this paper presents the first
piece of systematic evidence on this issue, one way or the other.
The third motivation of the paper comes from the U.S. government's concern
that the Foreign Corrupt Practices Act (FCPA) of 1977 may have undermined
the American firms' competitiveness in the overseas markets vis a vis
firms from Europe, Japan and elsewhere. The FCPA came as a by-product
of the Watergate hearings in the early 1970s, where many American firms
were discovered paying large bribes to foreign officials in addition to
contributing to domestic political parties. As a sign of the mood of the
day, the bill was passed unanimously in both the Senate and the House,
and was signed into law by President Carter. At the time the law was enacted,
it may have been hoped that other major source countries would follow
suit. But that has not happened so far. The FCPA has made the United States
the only source country in the world that penalizes its multinationals
or their officers with fines or jail terms for bribing foreign government
officials.
On a priori ground, the American multinationals may not necessarily dislike
the law. Aside from the moral position of the corporate officers, the
law may serve as a useful commitment device for them in the face of foreign
corrupt official's demand for bribery. The law allows them to say something
to the effect, "I would like to pay you. But I am sorry I can't.
If I do, I will go to jail." This commitment device is not available
to companies from other source countries. If the American firms have the
one and the only kind of technology that the host country needs, the American
firms may very well still capture the business but with a lower cost (because
of no bribery). In this case, the FCPA would not hinder the U.S. investment.
Alternatively, if the American firms can find a way to circumvent the
law (e.g., by using a close substitute for outright bribery payment),
their competitive position vis a vis other investors would not be affected
either. Hence, the effect of the FCPA on the American competitiveness
becomes an empirical one: Is it binding at the margin?
Using country dummies as a measure of corruption, Beck, Maher and Tschoegl
(1991) found a statistically significant but quantitatively small effect
of corruption on the U.S. export competitiveness. In the concluding chapter
of J. David Richardson's book (1993), Sizing Up U.S. Export Disincentives,
the author noted under the section titled "surprisingly small estimates"
(p131) that, "across-the-board regulatory burdens, such as procedures
mandated for all businesses by the Foreign Corrupt Practices Act, seemed
generally unimportant." The best and the most recent evidence on
U.S. FDI and exports was provided by James Hines, Jr. (1995). Controlling
for the growth of the host country GDP, Hines found evidence that corruption
negatively affects the growth of U.S.-controlled FDI during 1977-1982,
their capital/labor ratio, incidence of joint ventures, and aircraft exports.
He interpreted the findings as evidence that FCPA has undermined the American
firms' competitiveness relative to other countries.
There are some reasons to think that the Hines' interpretation may require
some additional evidence. First, corruption may reduce FDI from non-U.S.
investors to the extent that they feel morally obligated to avoid bribery.
Second, American firms may be just as clever at finding covert substitutes
for bribery payments as other investors4. Third, the degree
of corruption in host countries tends to be highly correlated with many
other dimensions of the government quality, such as extent of bureaucracy
and red tape, or quality of legal system. These features are likely to
affect non-U.S. investors as well. To attribute the U.S. FDI's negative
correlation with corruption measure to the FCPA, we need to control for
the response of all FDI to corruption5.
I will also investigate whether Japan is a special source country in
the sense that its investors may be less sensitive to corruption in host
countries. Popular press accounts and anecdotes give one an impression
that Japanese corporations have a higher propensity to bribe officials
at home and that this propensity may carry over to cross-border business
dealings. If this is true, it may give Japanese multinationals a competitive
edge in corruption-prone host countries. According to the logic of Encarnation
(1992), whatever helps the Japanese multinationals relative to the American
ones also helps its global competitive position vis a vis the U.S.
The classical theoretical work on corruption includes Nye (1970), Rose-Ackerman
(1975 and 1978) and Shleifer and Vishny (1993). In light of the literature,
let me be up front about the limitations of this paper. Susan Rose-Ackerman
(1978) made a distinction between bribery (including campaign contribution)
to erect or change the rules/laws to favor the payers, and bribery to
deviate from an honest implementation of the exiting rules/laws. Shleifer
and Vishny (1993) made a distinction between organized or efficient corruption
(the payers can get things done after a relatively well-defined bribe),
and disorganized or inefficient corruption (there is still a big residual
uncertainty even after the bribe). The measures of corruption6 used in this paper cannot capture this conceptual richness. I would suppose
that the survey-based corruption measure refers mainly to the administration
of rules/laws pertinent to foreign firms, and probably is weighted by
efficiency level as perceived by those who were surveyed.
Corruption can have many other detrimental effects on the host countries.
In economic sphere, corruption may reduce growth rate, possibly as a result
of reduced domestic investment (Paulo Mauro, 1995; Knack and Keefer, 1995;
Rodrik, 1996; and Kaufmann, 19967). In political economy terms,
corruption often contributes to an unfair income or wealth distribution.
In political terms, corruption can breed political instability. These
important aspects of corruption may interact with its effect on inward
FDI This paper does not explicitly study any of these effects.
The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the data set.
Section 3 reports the statistical results. And Section 4 provides concluding
remarks.
Data
The key explanatory variable is the two-year bilateral flows of foreign
direct investment(FDI) over 1990-91. I calculate the FDI flows as the
difference between the end-of-year stock data in 1989 and 1991. The FDI
stock data comes from the OECD data base covering fourteen source countries
including the seven the largest ones in the world: the United States,
Japan, Germany, the United Kingdom, France, Canada and Italy. It covers
forty-five host countries8. Many OECD member countries report
both outward FDI and inward FDI. I choose the outward FDI as it is more
likely to be consistent in definition for a given source country. I use
two-year flows rather than one-year data in order to reduce the impact
of year-to-year idiosyncratic shocks.
The data on 1989 host countries' tax rate on foreign corporations is
the minimum of the following two measures: the statutory marginal tax
on foreign corporations as reported by Price Waterhouse (1990), and tax
payment to the host governments by the foreign subsidiaries of American
firms divided by their total income in that country. The data on twenty
eight of the host countries are taken from Hines and Desai (1996, Appendix
Table 2). The rest (seventeen countries) are either obtained using the
Price Waterhouse source with the kind assistance of Mihir Desai or calculated
by me (for China).
I use two measures of corruption, both of which are based on surveys
of respondents. The first one was based on surveys conducted and organized
during 1980-83 by Business International (BI), now a subsidiary of the
Economist Intelligence Unit. BI reports a number of survey-based rankings
of country risk factors, of which "corruption" is one. The BI
corruption measure is an integer from one (most corrupt) to ten (least
corrupt) according to "the degree to which business transactions
involve corruption or questionable payments." The data is kindly
provided by Paolo Mauro, who collected them by hand from Bl's archives.
The second measure is compiled by Transparency International (TI), an
agency dedicated to fighting corruption worldwide. The TI index is scaled
from zero (most corrupt) to nine (least corrupt). The TI index itself
is an average of ten survey results on corruption over a number of years.
The averaging procedure used by the TI could reduce measurement error
if the errors in different surveys are independent. On the other hand,
the ratings on different countries are derived from different surveys,
potentially introducing inconsistency in the cross-country ratings. Fortunately,
the BI and TI indices are highly correlated (with a correlation coefficient
equal to 0.89). In the subsequent sections, I will report estimation results
using both measures, while concentrating the discussion on results using
the BI index.
To avoid awkwardness in interpreting the coefficient, I redefine "corruption"
measure in this paper to be ten minus the two respective indices, so that
zero for BI and one for TI indices indicate "no corruption,"
and nine for BI and ten for TI "the highest level of corruption."
The GDP and population data are from the International Monetary Fund's
International Financial Statistics data base. In a few cases where GDP
data are not available, GNP data are used instead. The wage and labor
compensation data are from International Labor Organization, with the
kind assistance of Xiaolun Sun.
Four other survey-based qualitative measures of barriers to investment
come from The 1996 World Competitive Report. They are restrictions on
cross-border ventures, on foreign investors' ability to exert corporate
controls, on their eligibility to bid for public sector contracts, and
on their ability to access host country's domestic capital markets.
The dummy on linguistic tie takes the value of one if the source and
host countries share a common language, and zero otherwise. The data on
distance measures the "greater circle distance" between the
economic centers in the sourcehost pair. Both data have been used in Frankel,
Stein and Wei (1995) and Wei (1996).
The data on 1990 adult literacy ratio is defined as one minus 1990 adult
illiteracy ratio. Adult illiteracy ratio comes from Table 1 of the World
Bank's World Development Report 1995, which cites the U.N. Educational,
Scientific, and Cultural Organization (UNESCO) as the original source.
The Report does not present illiteracy rate for high-income countries,
but contains a footnote that reads "according to UNESCO, illiteracy
is less than 5 percent." I assign 2.5 percent as the illiteracy rate
for these high-income countries. According to the World Bank Report's
technical notes (p231), "adult illiteracy is defined here as the
proportion of the population over the age of fifteen who cannot, with
understanding, read and write a short, simple statement on their everyday
life."
The information on 1990 total secondary school enrollment comes from
Table 28 of the same World Bank Report. The technical notes to the Table
(p241), the data are estimates of the ratio of children of all ages enrolled
in secondary school to the country's population of secondary-school-age
children. It notes that the definition of secondary school age "differs
among countries," and "is most commonly considered to be 12
to 17 years." It further notes that "late entry of more mature
students as well as repetition and the phenomenon of 'bunching' in final
grades can influence these ratios."
Table 1 reports summary statistics on some of the key variables in this
paper for the all host countries and for East Asia countries. We observe
that East Asian countries on average are more corrupt than other countries
in terms of either measure of corruption, and somewhat less stable politically,
both of which in principle may discourage foreign investment. On the other
hand, East Asian countries on average have lower tax rate and lower wage
rate, both of which in principle may encourage foreign investment.
Statistical Estimation
Preliminary
Double-log Linear Model
Does
Corruption Discourage FDI? The OLS Estimates
Modified Tobit
Estimation
The
myth of East Asian Exceptionalism
Are
American Investors More Sensitive to Corruption?
Preliminary Double-log
Linear Model
I will start with a preliminary linear model (after taking logarithm
for both the dependent variable, FDI, and most of the independent variables,
such as GDP and distance). The model will be estimated using the Ordinary
Least Squares (OLS) method. The dependent variable is the cumulative flows
of FDI in logarithm during 1990-91 from source country i to host country
j. Use "taxj" and "corruptionj"
to denote host country j's tax rate on foreign corporations and its corruption
level, respectively. Then, the basic regression specification is
log(FDIij) = Xyb g 1 taxj g 2 corruptionj ey
where X is a vector of control variables other than tax and corruption
that are relevant for determining the bilateral FDI. b, g1 and 92 are parameters.
I will implement a quasi-fixed effects model. That is, the X-vector in
all regressions will include source country dummies9. The source
country dummies are meant to capture all characteristics of the source
countries that may be relevant to its size of outward FDI, including its
GDP and level of development. In addition, differences in the definition
of FDI across source countries can be controlled for by the dummies under
the (somewhat audacious) assumption that these definitions are proportional
to each other except for an additive error term uncorrelated with other
regressors in the regression. I do not include host country dummies as
doing so would eliminate the possibility of estimating all the interesting
coefficients including the effects of tax and corruption.
Does Corruption
Discourage FDI? The OLS Estimates
Table 2 presents the results of the basic regressions using the Business
International (BI) index as a measure of corruption. In Column 1, I control
for the size of the host country by its GDP and population, both in logarithm,
the distance between the source and host countries, and a dummy for whether
they share a common language. The coefficient on the marginal tax rate
(on foreign investors) is negative and statistically significant at the
five percent level. A one percentage point increase in the marginal tax
rate reduces inward FDI by about five percent. The coefficient on the
corruption measure is also negative and significant. The numerical effect
is remarkably large. A one-grade increase in the corruption level is associated
with a sixteen percent reduction in the flow of FDI10, or approximately
equivalent to a three percentage point increase in the marginal tax rate.
In other words, a worsening in host government's corruption level from
that of Singapore (with a BI-rating of zero) to that of Mexico (with a
BI-rating of 6.75) is equivalent to about 21 percentage point11 increase in the marginal tax rate on foreigners.
There are other interesting observations from the first regression. The
coefficient on the distance variable is negative and statistically significant
at the five percent level: a one percent increase in distance is associated
with a 1.14 percent reduction in the FDI flow. Thus, international investment
to some extent is a* neighborhood event. On the other hand, the coefficient
on the linguistic dummy is positive and significant at the fifteen percent
level: sharing a common language or colonial history is associated with
a sizable increase in bilateral FDI flow. Some authors (e.g., Rauch, 1996a
and 1996b) have emphasized the importance of networks in business transactions.
While it is difficulty to measure the strength of network precisely, distance
and linguistic tie may capture part of it, and the evidence presented
here is consistent with the network notion.
Because the log(population) term is not statistically different from
zero, I drop this variable in other regressions reported in Table 2. One
may worry about possible endogeneity of the GDP variable. Since population
and GDP are highly correlated, I use log(population) as an instrumental
variable for Iog(GDP). Column 2 reports such an IV regression. Both tax
and corruption continue to show a negative effect on FDI. The point estimate
of corruption gets substantially larger.
Many countries effectively exempt foreign source income from domestic
taxation. So direct investment from these countries should be sensitive
to foreign tax rates. The tax codes of the United States, United Kingdom
and Japan allow their multinational firms to claim credit for taxes paid
to foreign governments (up to the limit of what they would have to pay
to the home governments if the foreign source income were derived domestically).
This could makes direct investment from these source countries insensitive
to foreign tax rate (up to a limit). On the other hand, foreign tax credit
can be claimed only when profits are repatriated. Many multinational firms
from U.S., UK and Japan choose to reinvest a substantial fraction of their
foreign income in the plants in the host country (Hines and Hubbard, 1990).
In this case, their firms may still be sensitive to host country tax rates.
For this reason, to what extent FDI from these three source countries
is sensitive to host countries' tax rate becomes an empirical question.
To investigate this, I add to the regression an interactive term, "ftci*tax-ratej,"
where ftc is a dummy variable taking the value of one if the source country
is either the U.S., UK or Japan. The result is in Column 3 of Table 2.
The coefficient is -0.01 and not different from zero at the ten percent
level. Hence, it appears that the FDIs from these three source countries
are just as sensitive to the 'tax rate in host countries as FDIs from
other source countries. More importantly, the estimated effects of tax
and corruption on FDI are unaffected by the inclusion of this variable.
Column 4 adds the host country's wage level (in logarithm) to the list
of regressors. This is motivated by the popular hypothesis that many FDIs
chase lowcost labor in the host countries. This suggests a negative correlation
between the size of inward FDI and hosts wage level. Contrary to the expectation,
the estimated coefficient for the wage variable is positive (0.50) and
significant at the ten percent level. Though it is not consistent with
the popular labor cost hypothesis, this finding echoes many other papers
in the literature12 . It is important to note that, for our
purpose, the coefficients for the tax rate and corruption measures remain
negative and statistically significant.
There is a reason to suspect that the specification in Column 4 may not
be a fair test of the low labor cost hypothesis. We know that some of
the FDIs move from developed countries to developing countries (primarily
as part of vertically integrated firms), but many move from developed
to developed countries (primarily in the form of horizontally integrated
firms). Implicitly if not explicitly, the labor cost hypothesis is postulated
only for the first type of FDIs. To account for this, I let the labor
cost to play potentially different roles for the two types of the FDIs.
Specifically, I create an OECD dummy for all host countries which are
members of OECD up to 1990. 1 add an interactive term, "OEC D*Iog
(wage)," and the dummy itself, "OECD," to the list of regressors.
The result is reported in Column 5. The coefficient for log(wage) term
now is negative and statistically significant, consistent with the FDls-chasing-low-labor-cost
story. For a non-OECD host country, a one percent increase in the wage
rate is associated with a 0.8 per cent reduction in inward FDls.
The positive coefficient on the OECD dummy indicates that all OECD host
countries tend to receive more FDIs than the sample average. A F-test
indicates that the sum of the two coefficients for log(wage) and the interactive
term (-0.78+1.28=0.5) is not different from zero. Hence, within the OECD
host countries, there is no relationship between the size of inward FDls
and the host country's wage level. In sum, this demonstrates the need
to separate the two types of FDIs when one investigates the effect of
host country labor cost. To my knowledge, this empirical finding is new
in the literature.
With the host country's labor cost taken into account in Column 5, the
coefficients for tax rate and corruption measures have changed only slightly.
So our basic qualitative results survive this extension.
Besides the labor cost story, one may conjecture that a host country's
education level, or its endowment of skilled labor may play an important
role in attracting inward FDI This is a key feature of the new FDI theory
of Markusen (1994) and Zhang(1996). As an extension, I ran three additional
regressions (not reported to save space) adding three different measures
of human capital in host countries, one at a time. They are literacy ratio,
enrollment of secondary schools, and per capita GDP, respectively. Somewhat
disappointingly, none of them is statistically significant. Again, the
coefficients on tax rate and corruption remain largely unchanged. I have
used labor compensation instead of wage rate in the regressions (not reported)
with same qualitative answers. But the number of observations is substantially
smaller for compensation than for wage data.
Modified Tobit Estimation
There is a potential problem with the double-log linear specification
in the previous subsection. Not all countries receive direct investment
from all source countries. These zero FDI observations are dropped from
the sample when a double-log specification is implemented. If it is the
case that the desired level of FDI based on the characteristics of the
host country and host-source relation is zero or negative, we have the
classic censored sample problem. Dropping these observations could lead
to inconsistency. Unfortunately, it is not feasible to apply the Tobit
specification while maintaining the double log structure on the two sides
of the equation, as the logarithm of zero (FDI) is undefined.
In(FDIij +A) = Xyb + uij if Xb + uij > In(A)
= In(A) if Xb + uij <= In(A)
In this section, I define a modified Tobit specification. where A is
a threshold parameter to be estimated. u is an i.i.d random variable with
mean zero and variance s2. In this specification, when Xb+u
exceeds a threshold value, InA, there will be a positive flow of foreign
investment; and when Xb+u is below the threshold value, the realized level
of foreign investment is zero (and desired level could be negative). Eaton
and Tamura (1996) pioneered a version of this specification.
I will implement the estimation with the maximum likelihood method (See
an Appendix for a derivation of the MLE estimator).
The basic regression results are reported in Table 3. In Column 1, 1
have as control variables the host country's GDP, the distance between
the host and source countries, and a possible linguistic/colonial connection
between the two. The key variables are host countries' tax rate and corruption.
Both variables produce negative coefficients that are statistically significant.
Hence, when zero observations are taken into account, we still find that
tax and corruption deter foreign direct investment.
In column 2, we add the log of population in the host country to the
list of control variables. It has a coefficient (0.00013) and statistically
significant. The point estimate for the tax effect gets somewhat smaller
(to -0,00331 from -0.00440). And that for the corruption effect gets slightly
larger (to -0.00012 from -0.00010).
Suppose b, and b2 are coefficient estimates for tax rate and corruption,
respectively. Given the specification, a 100/b1 percentage point change
in tax rate and a 1/b2 change in the rating of corruption would produce
the same amount of change in the FDI flow. Therefore, a one-step increase
in the corruption measure is equivalent to 100b2/b1 percentage points
increase in the tax rate. Using the estimates in Column 2, a one-step
increase in the corruption level is equivalent to a rise in the tax rate
by 3.6 percentage points, other things equal. An increase in corruption
level from that of Singapore (whose rating is zero) to that of Mexico
(whose rating is 6.76) is equivalent to raising the tax rate by 24 percentage
points.
In Column 3, we add an interactive term between tax rate and a dummy
indicating that the source countries offering foreign tax credit. The
point estimate of the coefficient is positive (0.90), indicating that
the FDI from the U.S., UK and Germany that grant foreign tax credits is
somewhat less sensitive to host countries' tax rate. However, as with
the OLS results, the coefficient variable is statistically not different
from zero at the ten percent level.
One may speculate that political stability promotes foreign investment,
and that corruption and political stability are negatively correlated.
The causality on the corruption/stability nexus can go both ways: official
corruption may breed public discontent, which may eventually topple the
government; alternatively, instable political environment induces officials
to have short horizons and to grab whatever rents available while they
can. It may be useful to investigate the independent effect of corruption
on FD1 after controlling for political stability.
In the next regression reported in Column 4, 1 include a measure of political
stability. The new variable produces a positive coefficient (0.085), which
is consistent with the notion that stable political regime in a host country
promotes inward foreign direct investment. On the other hand, the estimate
is only marginally significant at ' the fifteen percent level. More importantly
to our central discussion, the estimated effect of corruption on FDI is
little affected by the inclusion of the measure of political stability.
Using the estimates in Column 4, a one-step increase in corruption is
equivalent to rasing tax rate by three percentage points. An increase
in corruption from the Singapore level to Mexico level is similar to a
rise in tax rate by 21 percentage points13 .
Column 5 controls for source countries offering foreign tax credits.
This again does not change any result.
The labor cost variables appear to have contributed to explaining cross-country
variations in FDI in the earlier OLS estimations. In Table 4, we add labor
cost variables to the modified Tobit estimations. We again do this in
two ways. First, we add a measure of hourly wage cost in the host countries.
Second, we allow for possibly different effects between labor cost in
developing countries and that in OECD countries. The labor market variables
turn out to be insignificant in the Tobit specification. The estimates
on the effects of tax and corruption remain essentially intact.
The myth of East Asian
Exceptionalism
I now turn to the hypothesis that corruption has no or reduced effect
on FDI into the East Asian countries. To test this, I create an East Asia
dummy, "EastAsia," for the eight developing host countries in
the region that are part of the sample: The Philippines, Malaysia, Singapore,
Thailand, Korea, Taiwan, China and Hong Kong. I add an interactive term,
"EastAsia*Corruption," together with the dummy itself to the
basic specification. The result is reported in Table 4.
There are several interesting findings. First, the positive coefficient
on the EastAsia dummy indicates that the region has received more inward
FDI than what can be predicted based on GDP, population, proximity, and
linguistic tie to source countries. Second, controlling for the East Asia
effect, the effects of tax and corruption on FDI are still negative. A
one-step increase in the corruption measure is now equivalent to 5 percentage
point increase in the tax rate14 . Third, the coefficient on
the interaction term between EastAsia dummy and the corruption measure
is a small positive number, which could indicate that the effect of corruption
in East Asia on FDI is slightly smaller than elsewhere. But the estimate
is tiny in magnitude and not different from zero in a statistical sense
(even at the fifteen percent level). Hence, there is no support for the
hypothesis that corruption in East Asia has no or reduced effect on inward
FDI. Within East Asia, foreign investors would still prefer to go to a
less corrupt host country than a more corrupt one, just as they do elsewhere.
One may want to control for some possible outliers. In particular, Hong
Kong and Singapore are two special economies in the region. Both have
a reputation for having a clean government and predictable rule of law.
On the other end of the spectrum, China is reported to have rampant corruption.
It is possible that our earlier estimates are influenced by these observations.
To investigate this, I also add to the regression three separate dummies
for Hong Kong, Singapore and China as host countries. The results are
reported in the Columns 3 and 4 of Table 5.
It is interesting to observe that the coefficients for the China dummy
are negative (-0.81 and -0.89) and statistically significant. This means
that China is actually an underachiever as a host of FDI from the major
source countries in the sample15. This is reassuring for the
purpose of this paper in that foreign investors from the major source
countries did not show less sensitivity to China's rampant corruption.
On the other hand, the low FDI into China during 1990-91 could be part
of the after-effect of the Tiananmen Square Incident. In addition, the
direct investment from overseas Chinese in Hong Kong, Taiwan and elsewhere,
the largest source for China's inward FDI, could potentially behave differently
from the investors included in this sample.
It is perhaps surprising that, once controlling for the fact that all
East Asian countries receive lots of inward foreign investment, the coefficients
for Singapore and Hong Kong dummies are also negative. Using the estimates
in Column 4, the sum of the Singapore coefficient (-0.74) and the East
Asia coefficient (0.77) is not significantly different from zero according
to a F-test. The same is true for the Hong Kong effect. This means that
Singapore and Hong Kong are very similar to other nonEast Asian countries
as hosts of FDI
The most important observation from Columns 3 and 4, from the viewpoint
of the main question of this section, is that the effects of tax and corruption
on FDI remain unchanged after the inclusion of the dummies for China,
Singapore and Hong Kong. Foreign investors are still no less averse to
corruption in East Asia than elsewhere.
A measure of political stability in host government is added to the regressions
in Columns 5 and 6 with no noticeable change in terms of the main results.
To check the sensitivity of the results to the choice of corruption measures,
Table 6 replicates several key regressions in Table 5 using the TI index
rather an the BI index. All the main qualitative results are unchanged.
The estimated effect of corruption (and that of tax) on FDI is somewhat
larger. Hence, we conclude that the inference is not sensitive to the
choice of the corruption measure.
Are American
Investors More Sensitive to Corruption?
The Foreign Corrupt Practices Act makes the U.S. the only source country
that provides an explicit penalty to its firms for bribing foreign government
officials. In this section, I will examine whether or not American investors
are more sensitive to corruption than those from other source countries.
To accomplish this, I will add to the regression an interactive term,
"USi*Corruptionj," where "USi" is a dummy variable
taking the value of one if the source country is the United States and
zero otherwise. There are three plausible hypotheses.
(Hypothesis 1) Corruption discourages U.S. investors in the same way
as non-U.S. investors. In this case, the interactive term will have a
zero coefficient.
(Hypothesis 2) Corruption only discourages U.S. investors. Hence, the
interactive term will have a negative coefficient, and the generic corruption
measure will longer be negatively correlated with FDL
(Hypothesis 3) Corruption discourages FDl from all investors, but it
depresses that from the U.S. even more. In this case, the coefficients
on both the corruption measure and the interactive term will be negative
and significant.
The coefficient estimate on the newly added interactive term is -0. 12,
comparable in magnitude to the coefficient on the generic corruption measure.
Thus, the point estimate could be consistent with Hypothesis 3 above.
In fact, U.S. investors, could be twice as sensitive to corruption as
an average OECD investor. On the other hand, due to the large standard
error, the coefficient is only statistically different from zero at the
fifteen percent level, making it difficult to reject Hypothesis 1 above
at the ten percent level, that U.S. investors are sensitive to corruption,
but no more so than an average investor from other OECD countries.
There are several plausible, not mutually exclusive explanations for
the possibility that the American investors are equally but not more averse
to host country corruption relative to other investors. First, corruption
is often an indicator for general weak enforcement of contracts by host
governments, Byzantine bureaucracy and so on, that hurts every investor,
regardless of whether the source country government forbids bribery payment
by its companies. Second, to the extent that investors feel repulsive
about corruption, they may be deterred by it just as much as the Americans,
even without a formal law like the U.S. FCPA. Finally, when bribery becomes
a necessary part of the business deal, the American firms are just as
clever as other investors at finding covert means to pay it in spite of
the FCPA.
Using the same method, I also investigate the sensitivity of Japanese
investors to host country corruption: I will augment the regression in
Column 1 by an additional term, "Japani*Corruptionj," where
"Japani" is a dummy variable taking the value of one if the
source country is Japan and zero otherwise. The result is reported in
Column 2 of Table 7. This coefficient is positive (0.07), consistent with
the possibility that Japanese investors are somewhat less sensitive to
corruption than other investors. But the estimate is statistically not
different from zero.
It may be interesting to examine whether the U.S. and Japanese investments
in East Asia are any different from those elsewhere. To this end, I add
four new variables to the specification in Column 2. Two of the variables
are meant to capture any special factor that may influence their investments
in East Asia (but not elsewhere): US*EastAsia, and Japan*EastAsia. Two
others are meant to measure if their sensitivity to corruption in East
Asia is any different from that in other parts of the world: US*Corruption*EastAsia,
and Japan*Corruption*EastAsia. The result is reported in Column 3. As
it turns out, the four new variables do not produce coefficients that
are different from zero at the ten percent level. Hence, these two major
source countries' investments in East Asia, or their sensitivity to corruption
in the region, are not unusual relative to the prediction of the overall
model. On the other hand, once we have added these four variables, the
coefficient on the interactive term, "Japanj*Corruptionj," becomes
larger (to 0.13) and statistically significant at the five percent level.
Hence, there is now some support for the notion that Japanese investors
are somewhat less sensitive to corruption.
In Column 4, a measure of political stability is added to the regression.
Political stability is still found to promote inward foreign investment.
Controlling for this, corruption still discourages foreign investment.
U.S. investors do not behave differently from others in any statistically
significant way. On the other hand, Japanese investors appear to be somewhat
less sensitive to corruption. Investors from both U.S. and Japan appear
to dislike corruption in East Asia exactly the same way as they do in
other parts of the world.
Using the Transparency International's Index for corruption, Table 8
replicates some of the key regressions in Table 7 with broadly similarly
results. Hence, the inferences derived from Table 7 do not depend on the
particular choice of the corruption measure.
This paper studies the effect of taxation and corruption on international
direct investment from fourteen source countries to forty-five host countries.
There are three central findings. First, an increase in either the tax
rate on multinational firms or corruption level in the host governments
would reduce inward foreign direct investment. An increase in the corruption
level from that of Singapore (a BI-rating of zero) to that of Mexico (a
BI-rating of 6.75) is equivalent to raising the tax rate by 2124 percentage
points.
Second, there is no evidence that international investors are less sensitive
to corruption in East Asia. It is appropriate to add some comments here
on the FDI in China. Though the size of annual inflow is large, over 60%
of it in each of the last ten years came from overseas Chinese, notably
those in Hong Kong16. In other words, China is not a typical
host country. FDI from the ten largest source countries in the world,
all of them members of the OECD, accounts for a relatively small portion
of total FDI going into China. In the estimation reported in this paper,
China is in fact an underachiever as a host for FDI from the major source
countries. This is consistent with the inference of this paper that investors
from the major source countries prefer to go to less corrupt countries.
What is intriguing is that the overseas Chinese are apparently less sensitive
to corruption, possibly because they are better able to use personal connection
to substitute for the rule of law, a subject awaiting fruitful future
research.
Third, American investors are averse to host country corruption but not
necessarily more so than other investors, in spite of its unique Foreign
Corrupt Practices Act. There is also some weak evidence that Japanese
investors are less sensitive to corruption, possibly correlated with the
way business transactions are conducted in Japan.
There are other interesting findings. For example, there is some support
for the labor cost hypothesis of FDI for non-OECD host countries. In the
OLS estimations, I find a negative correlation between the wage level
and the size of inward FDI for non-OECD hosts but zero correlation for
OECD hosts. However, this result does not carry over to the modified Tobit
estimation. Also, consistent with the importance of networks, sharing
a common linguistic tie between the source and host countries and geographic
proximity between the two are found to be associated with a sizable increase
in the bilateral FDI flow.
ENDNOTES
1 "Transition,"7(9-10), p. 9,Sept/Oct., 1996.
2 According to The Wall Street Journal ("Smugglers Stoke
B.A.T.'s Cigarette Sales in China," December 18, 1996), the Chinese
consume a huge quantity of foreign-made cigarettes ("one in every
three cigarettes is smoked in China."), but 90% of the imports do
not pay duty. The British American Tobacco (BAT) company is the largest
supplier of foreign cigarettes in China. In 1995, the company sold 400
million cigarettes that were duty-paid, 3 billion in duty-free shop, 4
billion in special economic zones (SEZs), many of which transported illegally
to other parts of China, and 38 billion to retailers who smuggled their
way directly into China. Conversations with Hong Kong businessmen indicate
that there is a well-developed fee-for-service business in Hong Kong to
smuggle goods through the Chinese customs. There are at least four different
ways to circumvent the Chinese tariffs, most of which involve paying bribery
to Chinese customs officials. A business consultant who works for a major
U.S.-owned consulting firm in Hong Kong indicated that 90% of foreign
wine in the Chinese market was also smuggled into the country.
3 Hines (1995) did find a significantly negative effect of
corruption on U.S. FDl, and interpreted it as a result of the Foreign
Corrupt Practices Act. I will return to this later.
4 Conversations with Chinese businessmen and officials suggests
that outright financial payment is not the dominant bribery form in China
(because bribe-taking officials can be prosecuted even in the Chinese
court). Instead, sponsoring a "study trip" (read: expense-paid
tours) for officials to a foreign country (particularly that of the home
country of the multinational firm) and providing financial support for
family members of the officials to study or work in a foreign country
are popular and legal ways to curry favor with the corrupt officials.
Anecdotal evidence suggests that American firms are just as creative and
active in doing these as investors from any other country, if not more.
5 Hines attempted to control for this with total inward FDI
as one of the regressors. The data on total FDI are from the World Bank's
World Tables, and were originally reported by host countries as part of
their national income and product accounts. The definitions and calculation
methods differ considerably among the countries. Consequently, the data
may have large measurement errors. In addition, since total FDI is affected
by many of the same factors as the U.S. FDI, it is likely to be correlated
with the error term in regressions where the U.S. FDI is the dependent
variable. This measure of total FDI is not statistically significant in
any of his regressions (Hines, 1995, Table 2).
6 A more detailed explanation is in the next section.
7 Both Knack and Keefer (1995) and Rodrik (1996) employ a
composite measure of institutional quality, which is composed of rule
of law, repudiation of contracts by governments, expropriation risk, quality
of bureaucracy, as well as corruption in the government. These indicators
are highly correlated with each other. Kaufmann (1996, summary, page i)
found, among participants in Harvard University's special mid-career programs
and short-term workshops during the summer of 1996. a majority "consider
corruption about the most important challenge for economic development
and growth for their countries, and also many regard vested financial
interest and corruption as a key reason for the lack of sufficient economic
reform progress in recent times."
8 The number of host countries is constrained by the availability
of data on tax on foreign corporations and measure of corruption.
9 Because the 14 source countries covers a substantial fraction
of the universe of all FDl flows in the world, a fixed effects regression
may be more appropriate than a random effects model (Hsiao, 1986). All
regressions in this paper will have a constant and seven source country
dummies (the U.S., Japan, Germany, France, UK, Canada and Italy). FDl
from other source countries are relatively sparse. In order to avoid singularity
or near-singularity problems in the estimation, I merge all the remaining
source country dummies into one constant.
10 exp(-O. 17)-l = -0. 156
11 (-0.1566.75)/(-0.05) = 21.1.
12 Wheeler and Mody (1992) reported a positive correlation
between wage level and inward FDI, exactly opposite to the hypothesis
of FDI chasing low labor costs.
13 100'(0.11/3.49)*6.75=21.28.
14 100(0. 16/2.91) = 5.49.
15 Using data from a different source and a simpler model
that controls for size, education level and distance from the source countries
but not for the effects of tax and corruption, Wei (1996) reported that
China is an underachiever as a host of direct investment from the U.S.,
UK, Germany and France.
16 Part of the FDl from Hong Kong recorded by the official
Chinese statistics is in fact disguised Chinese domestic capital in order
to take advantage of preferential treatment (e.g., reduced taxes) the
government accords to foreign firms. Another (smaller) part of the Hong
Kong investment is likely to be U.S. or other western investment in disguise
in order to take advantage of the network connections that Hong Kong partners
may have in China. No exact estimates on these two categories are available.
References
Beck, Paul J., Michael W. Maher, and Adrian E. Eschoegl, 1991, "The
Impact of the Foreign Corrupt Practices Act on US Exports, " Managerial
and Decision Economics, 12:295-303.
Desai, Mihir, and James R. Hines, Jr., 1996, "'Basket' Cases: International
Joint Ventures After the Tax Reform Act of 1986," NBER Working Paper
5755, September.
Eaton, Jonathan and Akiko Tamura, 1996, "Japanese and U.S. exports
and investment as conduits of growth," in Takatoshi Ito and Anne
0. Krueger (1996), pp51-72.
Encarnation, Dennis J., 1992, Rivals Beyond Trade: America versus Japan
in Global Competition, Ithaca and London: Come[[ University Press.
Frankel, Jeffrey, Ernesto Stein, and Shang-Jin Wei, 1995, "Trading
Blocs and the Americas: The Natural, the Unnatural, and the Super-natural,"
Journal of Development Economics, 47: 61-95, June.
Froot, Kenneth, 1993, Foreign Direct Investment, Chicago and London:
University of Chicago Press.
Hines, James, 1995, "Forbidden Payment: Foreign Bribery and American
Business After 1977," NBER Working Paper 5266, September.
Hines, James R., Jr. and Glenn Hubbard, 1990, "Coming Home to America:
Dividend Repatriations by U.S. Multinationals," in Assaf Razin and
Joel Slemrod, eds., Taxation in the Global Economy. Chicago: University
of Chicago Press, pp161-200.
Hsiao, Cheng, 1986, Analysis of Panel Data, Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
International Labor Organization, 1995, International Labor Yearbook,
Geneva: International Labor Organization.
Ito, Takatoshi and Anne 0. Krueger, 1996, Financial Deregulation and
Integration in East Asia, Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press.
Lawrence, Robert, Dani Rodrik, and John Whalley, 1996, Emerging Agenda
for Global Trade: High Stakes for Developing Countries, Policy Essay No.
20, Overseas Development Council, Washington, DC.
Markusen, James R., 1984, "Multinationals, Multi-Plant Economies,
and the Gains from Trade, " Journal of International Economics, 16:
205-226.
Markusen, James R., 1995, "The Boundaries of Multinational Firms
and the Theory of International Trade," Journal of Economic Perspectives
9: 169-189.
Mauro, Paolo, 1995, "Corruption and Growth," Quarterly Journal
of Economics, 110: 681-712.
Nye, Joseph S., 1967, "Corruption and Political Development: A Cost-Benefit
Analysis," American Political Science Review, 61: 417-427, June.
Kaufmann, Daniel, 1996, "Listening to Developing Countries Spell
the C Word: The 'Tackling-Corruption-Is-Taboo' Myth Meets Some Evidence,"
Unpublished, Harvard Institute for International Development.
Knack, Stephen and Philip Keefer, 1995, "Institutions and Economic
Performance: Cross-Country Tests Using Alternative Institutional Measures,"
Economics and Politics, 7(3): 207-227, November.
Kravis, I.B., and Robert E. Lipsey, 1982, "Location of Overseas
Production and Production for Export by U.S. Multinational Firms,"
Journal of International Economics 12:201-223.
Rauch, James, 1996a, "Networks versus Markets in International Trade,"
NBER Working Paper 5617, June.
Rauch, James, 1996b, "Trade and Search: Social Capital, Sogo Shosha,
and Spillovers," NBER Working Paper 5618, June.
Richardson, J. David, 1993, Sizing Up U.S. Export Disincentives, Institute
for International Economics, Washington, DC.
Rodrik, Dani, 1996a, "Labor Standands in International Trade: Do
They Matter and What Do We Do About Them?" in R. Lawrence, D.Rodrik,
and J. Whalley (1996).
Rodrik, Dani, 1996b, "Institutions and Economic Performance in East
and Southeast Asia," Unpublished, Kennedy School of Government, Harvard
University, October.
Rose-Ackerman, Susan, 1975, "The Economics of Corruption, "
Journal of Public Economics, 4:187-203.
Rose-Ackerman, Susan, 1978, Corruption: A Study in Political Economy,
New York: Academic Press.
Shah, A. and J. Slemrod, 1990, "Tax Sensitivity of Foreign Direct
Investments: an Empirical Assessment," Policy Research and External
Affairs Working Paper, No. 434. The World Bank, Washington, DC.
Shleifer, Andrei and Robert W. Vishny, 1993, "Corruption,"
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108: 599-617.
Wei, Shang-Jin, 1996a, "Foreign Direct Investment in China: Sources
and Consequences," in T. Ito and A. Krueger (1996), pp 77-101.
Wei, Shang-Jin, 1996b, "How Reluctant are Nations in Global Integration?"
Unpublished, Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University, November.
Revised from "Intra-national versus International Trade: How Stubborn
Are Nations in Global Integration?" NBER Working Paper 5531, April.
Wheeler, David, and Ashoka Mody, 1992, "International Investment
Location Decisions: The Case of U.S. Firms," Journal of International
Economics 33:57-76.
World Bank, 1995, World Development Report 1995, Oxford University Press.
Zhang, Kevin, 1996, "A Model of International Trade with Vertical
Multinationals," University of Colorado Working Paper.
|